Next Article in Journal
Gibbs–Appell Equations in Finite Element Analysis of Mechanical Systems with Elements Having Micro-Structure and Voids
Next Article in Special Issue
Generalized Vector Quasi-Equilibrium Problems
Previous Article in Journal
Reachable Set Estimation and Controller Design for Linear Time-Delayed Control System with Disturbances
Previous Article in Special Issue
On Bilevel Monotone Inclusion and Variational Inequality Problems
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

Proximal Analytic Center Cutting Plane Algorithms for Variational Inequalities and Nash Economic Equilibrium

Mathematics Department, Saskatchewan Polytechnic, Saskatoon, SK S7K 3R5, Canada
Mathematics 2024, 12(2), 177; https://doi.org/10.3390/math12020177
Submission received: 20 November 2023 / Revised: 19 December 2023 / Accepted: 28 December 2023 / Published: 5 January 2024
(This article belongs to the Special Issue Variational Inequality and Mathematical Analysis)

Abstract

:
In this study, we proposed proximal analytic center cutting plane algorithms for solving variational inequalities whose domains are normal regions. Our algorithms stop with a solution of the variational inequality after a finite number of iterations, or we may find a sequence that converges to the solution of the variational inequality. We introduced the definition of the Nash economic equilibrium solution over a normal region and proved a sufficient condition for our Nash economic solution. An example of Nash equilibrium over a normal region is also provided. Our proximal analytic center cutting plane algorithms are constructive proofs of our Nash equilibrium problems.

1. Preliminaries

Cutting plane methods for optimization have a long history that goes back at least to a fundamental paper by Kelley [1]. The theoretical approach of the analytic center cutting plane methods started from Gon and Vial [2]. du Merle [3] developed an implementation of the method of the prototype, which was successfully applied to solve several nontrivial convex optimization problems [4,5]. Some later developments of the analytic center cutting plane methods have been proposed for solving various variational inequalities, e.g., [6,7,8,9].
We present two proximal analytic center cutting plane algorithms for solving variational inequalities whose domains are normal regions.
Our proximal analytic center cutting plane algorithms are also constructive solutions to our Nash economic equilibrium problems.
This study contains a detailed description of computational schemes of algorithms and provides the theoretical proofs of their convergence to the desired solution.
Suppose X is a non-empty subset of the n-dimensional Euclidean space R n , and F: X R n is a function. We call that a point x*X is a solution of the variational inequality VI [F, X] if
F ( x * ) T ( x x * ) 0 , x X .
The point x*X is a solution of the dual variational inequality VID (F, X) if
F ( x ) T ( x x * ) 0 , x X .
Given VI[F, X] (VID[F, X]), the gap function is defined as
g X ( x ) = max y X F ( x ) T ( x y ) , x X   ( f X ( x ) = max y X F ( y ) T ( x y ) , x X ) .
A point x * X is said to be a ε-solution of the variational inequality (1) if g X ( x * ) ε , for given ε > 0 .
A function F: X R n is pseudomonotone on X if ∀ xX
F ( x ) T ( y x ) 0 F ( y ) T ( y x ) 0 , y X .
It is known that (see Auslender [10]), if F is continuous, then a solution x*X of VID (F, X) is a solution of VI (F, X); and if F is continuous pseudomonotone, then x*X is a solution of VI (F, X) if and only if it is a solution of VID (F, X).
It is known that the following Lemma 1 holds.
Lemma 1.
A point x* ∈ X is a solution of VI[F, X] (VID[F, X]) if and only if  g X ( x * ) = 0  ( f X ( x * ) = 0 ).
The convex hull of a set B R n is the set
c o n ( B ) = { i = 1 l α i x i ; x i B , i = 1 l α i = 1 , α i 0 } .
A polytope is a set P R n which is the convex hull of a finite set.
A polyhedron is a set
{ x R n ; A T x b }     R n ,
where b R n , and A is an m × n matrix.
A polytope is a polyhedron. The following intuitively clear but nontrivial to prove result is essentially due to Farkas [11], Minkowski [12], and Weyl [13]:
Lemma 2.
P is a polytope if and only if it is a bounded polyhedron.
In the sequel, we assume that a polytope always has a non-empty interior.
Definition 1.
A subset X ⊆  R n  is said to be a normal region if it is a closed bounded set and if there exists a sequence of polytopes {Cj}, which satisfies
CjCj+1 (j = 1, ⋯),
such that
( j = 1 C j ) c = X .
The proof of the following Theorem 1 is trivial.
Theorem 1.
A closed, bounded, convex region X ⊆ R n  is a normal region.
We denote X c the topological closure of X.
Theorem 2.
A subset X ⊆ R n  is a normal region if there exists a uniformly bounded sequence of polytopes {Cj}, Cj ⊆ X (j = 1, ⋯), such that
( j = 1 C j ) c = X .
Proof. 
Actually, let
C j = c o n ( i = 1 j C j ) .
Then, the sequence { C j } satisfies the conditions in Definition 1. □
Definition 2.
A subset X ⊆ R n  is a unbounded normal region if there exists a sequence of bounded normal regions X j X (j = 1, 2, …), such that each Xj contains all boundary points of X, and
j = 1 X j = X .
Actually, a subset X R n is a bounded or unbounded normal region if and only if it is a bounded or unbounded convex region.

2. Proximal Analytic Center Cutting Plane Algorithms

This section modifies the method in Shen and Pang [6] and presents proximal analytic center cutting plane algorithms for solving variational inequality VI[F, X], whose domains are normal regions.
From now on, we make the following assumptions: for each x, yX, given any ε ¯ = ( ε , ε , , ε ) T R n , δ ¯ = ( δ , δ , , δ ) T R n , where ε , δ ( 0 , 1 ) , we can always find F ¯ x R n and F ¯ y R n such that
(i)
F ( x ) F ¯ x F ( x ) + ε ¯ , F ( y ) F ¯ y F ( y ) + δ ¯
(ii)
F ¯ y F ¯ x if y x , no matter the relationship between ε ¯ and δ ¯ ,
(iii)
F ¯ y F ¯ x L y x , where L is a constant.
Assume the auxiliary Γ ( x , y ) : R n × R n R m be a mapping that is continuous in x and y, strong monotone with respect to y with a constant M > 0, i.e.,
( Γ ( y , x ) Γ ( z , x ) ) T ( y z ) M y z 2 , y , z X ,
Consider the auxiliary variational inequality associated with Γ , whose solution ω ( x ) satisfies
( Γ ( ω ( x ) , x ) Γ ( x , x ) + F ¯ x ) T ( y ω ( x ) ) 0 , y , z X .
In view of the strong monotonicity of Γ ( x , y ) with respect to y, this auxiliary variational inequality has a unique solution (Goffin, Luo, and Ye [7]).
For any polytope { x R n ; A T x b } , { x R n ; A T x + s = b , s = ( s 1 , s 2 , , s n ) , s i 0 } is associated with the potential function φ = i = 1 n ln s i . An approximate analytic center, introduced by Goffin, Luo, and Ye [7], is the maximizer of the potential function φ and the unique solution of the system
A T z = 0 A T x + s = b Z T s e η < 1 ,
where z is a dual vector, and Z the diagonal matrix built upon z.
Let X R n be a normal region, there exists a sequence of polytopes {Cj} satisfying CjCj+1 (j = 1, 2, ⋯) such that
( j = 1 C j ) c = X .
Then, there is a sequence of variational inequalities VI[F, Cj] (j = 1, 2, ⋯) from the original variational inequality VI[F, X], where the polytope Cj is given by the linear inequalities A j x = b j , x, bj R n , and Aj is an m × n matrix, (j = 1, 2, ⋯).
The following Algorithm 1 extends Algorithm 3.1 in Shen and Pang [6] from a feasible region of polytope to a normal region.
Algorithm 1
Assume X is a bounded normal region. Let ε ( 0 , 1 ) and α ( 0 , M ) be two constant. Set k = 0, j = 1, Ak = Aj, bk = bj, εk = ε, and
C j k = { x R n : A j k x b j k } .
Step 1 (Computation of the approximate analytic center). Find an approximate
analytic center x j k of C j k = { x R n : A j k x b j k } .
Step 2 (Stopping criterion). If g X ( x j k ) = 0, then stop.
Else go to Step 3.
Step 3 (Computation of a 1 / j solution). Find x j k of C j k = { x R n : A j k x b j k }
If g C j k ( x j k ) 1 / j then increase j by 1 and go to Step 1.
Else go to Step 4.
Step 4 (Solving the approximate auxiliary variational inequality problem). Find ω ( x j k ) ,
such that
( Γ ( ω ( x j k ) , x j k ) Γ ( x j k , x j k ) + F ¯ x k ) T ( y ω ( x j k ) ) 0 , y X ,
where F ¯ x j k satisfies F ( x j k ) F ¯ x j k F ( x j k ) + ε ¯ x j k , ε ¯ x j k = ( ε k , ε k , , ε k ) T R n .
Step 5 (construction of the approximate cutting plane). Let
y j k = x j k + ρ l k , j ( ω ( x j k ) x j k ) and G ¯ x j k = F ¯ y j k , where lk,j is the smallest integer
that satisfies
F ¯ x j k + ρ l k , j ( ω ( x j k ) x j k ) T ( x j k ω ( x j k ) ) α ω ( x j k ) x j k 2 ,
where F ¯ x j k + ρ l k , j ( ω ( x j k ) x j k ) T satisfies
F ( x j k ) + ρ l k ( ω ( x j k ) x j k ) ) F ¯ x k + ρ l k , j ( ω ( x j k ) x j k ) F ( x j k + ρ l k , j ( ω ( x j k ) x j k ) ) + ε ¯ k
where ε ¯ k = ε x k + ρ l k ( ω ( x k ) x k ) = ( ε k , ε k , , ε k ) T
Let H j k = { x : G x j k T ( x x j k ) = 0 } ,
A j k + 1 = A j k G ¯ x j k , b j k + 1 = b j k G ¯ x j k x j k .
Increase k by 1 and go to Step 1.
End of Algorithm 1.
Theorem 3.
Algorithm 1 either stops with a solution of the variational inequality VI(F, X) after a finite number of iterations, or there exists a sequence in X that converges to the solution of VI(F, X).
Proof. 
For any given j, ∃xjCj, such that g C j ( x j ) < 1 / j , (j = 1, 2, …), then
g C j ( x j ) 0 , j .
Because X is a bounded set, there exists a subsequence of {xj} and a point x*X such that the subsequence converges to x * X . We may assume that lim j x j = x * .
Since X is closed, y 0 X such that g X ( x j ) = max y X F ( x j ) ( x j y ) = F ( x j ) ( x j y 0 ) . And noting that ( j = 1 C j ) c = X , y i j = 1 C j such that lim i y i = y 0 , and for given j
F ( x j ) ( x j y 0 ) , i .
So, ε > 0 , N , for i N
0 F ( x j ) ( x j y 0 ) F ( x j ) ( x j y i ) < ε .
There is a subsequence of { C j } , and without a loss of generosity, we may assume { C j } itself, which satisfies that y j C j , j = 1 , 2 , . Therefore, for j N
0 g X ( x j ) g C j ( x j ) = F ( x j ) ( x j y 0 ) max y C j F ( x j ) ( x j y ) g X ( x j ) F ( x j ) ( x j y j ) < ε .
On the other hand, the continuity of g X implies that
g X ( x * ) g X ( x j ) 0 , j .
Consequently,
g X ( x * ) g X ( x * ) g X ( x j ) + g X ( x j ) g C j ( x j ) + g C j ( x j ) 0 , j .
Therefore,
g X ( x * ) = max y X F ( x * ) ( x * y ) = 0 .
Which concludes that x* is a solution of VI(F, X). The proof is complete. □
By use of our Algorithm 1, we are going to present the following Algorithm 2 to solve variational inequality VI(F, X) over an unbounded normal region X.
We can find a sequence of bounded normal regions Xj (j = 1, 2, …), such that each Xj contains all boundary points of X and
j = 1 X j = X .
We note that each variational inequality VI [F, Xj] has a unique solution x j * X j (j = 1, 2, …). And, when j is large enough, say j > N, the unique solution x * of the VI[F, X] satisfies that x * X j , j > N .
Algorithm 2
Assume X is an unbunded normal region. Set j = 1.
Step 1 (Computation of a sequence x j l X j such that x j 1 x j l 1 / j , ( l = 2 , 3 , ))
By use of Algorithm 1, computing a sequence { x j l } l = 1   X j such that
lim l x j l = x j * and x j 1 x j l 1 / j , ( l = 2 , 3 , .), (and let l , one
has x j 1 x j * 1 / j , although x j * is still unknown yet).
Step 2 (Stopping criterion). If g X ( x j l ) = 0 for any of l = 1 , 2 , , then stop.
Else go to Step 1.
End of Algorithm 2.
Theorem 4.
Algorithm 2 either stops with a solution of the variational inequality VI(F, X) after a finite number of iterations, or there exists a sequence in X that converges to the solution of VI(F, X).
Proof. 
Algorithm 2 stops with a solution of VI(F, X), or we can find sequences { x j l } l = 1 X j X such that lim l x j l = x j * (j = 1, 2, …), and x j * = x * if j > N, i.e., lim k x j k = x * (although x * is still unknown) if j > N. Therefore, from Step 1, one obtains
x j 1 x * 1 / j , j > N .
Then, take the sequence { x j 1 } j = 1 X (consisting of the first term of each sequence { x j l } l = 1 X j , j = 1, 2, …), and one has
x j 1 x k 1 x j 1 x * + x * x k 1 1 / j + 1 / k 0 , j , k .
Hence, { x j 1 } j = 1 X is a Cauchy sequence and so is convergent. From (2), one obtains lim j x j 1 = x * , which completes the proof. □

3. Nash Economic Equilibrium Application

Economic equilibrium is a condition or state in which economic forces are balanced. These economic variables remain unchanged from their equilibrium values in the absence of external influences. Economic equilibrium may also be defined as the point at which supply equals demand for a product, with the equilibrium price existing where the hypothetical supply and demand curves intersect. Economists can usually explain the past and sometimes predict the future, but not without help. One of the most important tools at their disposal is the Nash equilibrium, named after John Nash [14], who won a Nobel Prize in 1994 for his discovery. There were plenty of discussions followed after Nash, e.g., some recent approaches can be seen in Fischer [15], Faraci [16], and Boilan [17].
In this section, we explain that our proximal analytic center cutting plane algorithms can be used to solve some practical problems whose domains are normal regions, e.g., Nash economic equilibrium problems over normal regions.
Consider an oligopolistic economy in which a homogeneous product is supplied by n firms. Let p(σ) denote the inverse demand function, which is the price at which consumers will purchase a quantity σ. If each firm supplies qi units of the product, then the total supply is
σ q = i = 1 n q i .
We denote by h i ( q i ) the i-th firm’s total cost of supplying qi units of the product; the profit of the i-th firm is given by
φ i ( q ) = q i p ( σ q ) h i ( q i ) .
A vector q * = ( q 1 * , q 2 * , , q n * ) is a said to be a Nash equilibrium solution if it is an optimal solution to the problem
max q K φ i ( q ) = max q K [ q i p ( σ q + σ i * ) h i ( q i ) ] .
where K is the box-constrained set (see Konnov and Volotskaya [18]),
K = { x R n ; 0 a j x j b j + } ,
aj are constants, bj are either constants or +∞ (j = 1, …, n). And σ i * = j = 1 , j i n q j * (i = 1, 2, …, n).
The Clarke–Rokafellar generalized derivatives of h at p0 in the direction d is defined by
h ( p 0 , d ) = sup ε > 0 lim sup p ( h , p 0 ) t 0 + inf e B ε ( d ) h ( p + t e ) h ( p ) t ,
where B ε ( d ) = { e X : e d < ε } , t 0 + means that t > 0 and t 0 , p ( h , p 0 ) indicates that both p p 0 and h ( p ) h ( p 0 ) .
The Clarke–Rokafellar subdifferential of h at p0 is given by
h ( p 0 ) = { p X : ( p , d ) h ( p 0 , d ) , d X } .
Let
G i ( q ) = p ( σ q ) q i p ( σ q   ) , ( i = 1 , 2 , , m ) .
From Golshtein and Tretyakov [19], as well as Murphy, Sherali, and Soyster [20], a vector is a Nash equilibrium solution in the oligopolistic economy if and only if it is a solution to the problem
G ( q * ) T ( q q * ) + i = 1 n h i ( q i * ) ( q i q i * ) 0 , q K .
where K = { x R n ; 0 a j x j b j + } .
Write F ( q ) = G ( q ) + h ( q ) , then
F ( q * ) T ( q q * ) 0 , q K .
Similarly, we can introduce the Nash equilibrium solution in the oligopolistic economy if the domain is a normal region X:
A Nash equilibrium solution in the oligopolistic economy can be defined as a solution of the variational inequality VI[F, X]
F ( q * ) T ( q q * ) 0 , q X ,
if X is a normal region.
Example 1.
The following mathematical model is used to calculate the remaining loan balance of a fixed mortgage loan. The mortgage payment amount should be paid periodically for m periods on a mortgage amount L at a periodic interest rate of r 1 . After r 2  periods for full amortization m periods ( r 2 m ), the remaining balance B  of the loan is given by
B = L ( 1 + r 1 ) m ( 1 + r 1 ) r 2 ( 1 + r 1 ) m 1 .
Assume one would like to consider a selling price r 3 that satisfies
r 3 D + L B = D + L L ( 1 + r 1 ) m ( 1 + r 1 ) r 2 ( 1 + r 1 ) m 1
L L ( 1 + r 1 ) m ( 1 + r 1 ) r 2 ( 1 + r 1 ) m 1 ,
where D is the down payment at the beginning of the mortgage.
If there are n = (l1, l2, …, ln) mortgage providers in the same mortgage rate, p = r1 = p(σ). Mortgage provider li provides a mortgage amount of qi (i = 1, 2, …, n). Then, qi are all functions of r1, r2, and r3.
Let Y = Y (r1, r2, r3) be the convex region given by (5), where 0 < q1 ≤ M < ∞ for a given M. Then,
max q K φ i ( q ) = max q K [ q i p ( q i + σ i * ) h i ( q i ) ] = max y Y [ q i p ( q i + σ i * ) h i ( q i ) ]
which is an example of Nash equilibrium over a convex region.
Therefore, by Example 1, a domain of a Nash equilibrium problem may be a normal region, and so our proximal analytic center cutting plane methods can be applied to solve it.
A function F: X R n is said to be strictly pseudomonotone on X if q * X
F ( q * ) T ( q q * ) 0 F ( q ) T ( q q * ) > 0 , q X , q q * .
Theorem 5.
Let X ⊆ R n  be a normal region and F: X → R n  a continuous and strictly pseudomonotone function, then the Nash equilibrium (4) has one and only one solution.
Proof. 
q , q j = 1 C j , i , j such that q C i and q C j . Without loss of generality, we suppose that i j , then q , q C i . Due to the convexity of C i , we have
α q + ( 1 α ) q C i j = 1 C j , α [ 0 , 1 ] .
Which means that j = 1 C j is convex. It is easy to see that the closure of any convex set is convex. Therefore, X = ( j = 1 C j ) c is a convex and compact set in R n . From Hartman and Stampacchia [21], the Nash equilibrium (4) has solutions.
On the other hand, assume that q * is a solution of the Nash equilibrium (4); then,
F ( q * ) T ( q q * ) 0 , q X .
Due to the strict pseudomonotonicity of F, we have
F ( q ) T ( q q * ) > 0 , q X , q q * .
i.e.,
F ( q ) T ( q * q ) < 0 , q X , q q *
Which indicates that q X * with q q * is not a solution of (2). Therefore, the Nash equilibrium (2) has at most one solution. We complete the proof. □

4. Final Remarks

Remark 1.
The study is connected with the application of the proposed proximal analytic center cutting plane techniques to the analysis of the Nash equilibrium problems in models of oligopolistic economy stated as problems of variational inequalities. Our proximal analytic center cutting plane algorithms are constructive proof of the existence of our Nash equilibrium solutions in Section 3.
Remark 2.
We presented proximal analytic center cutting plane algorithms for solving variational inequalities, which extended the algorithms over polytopes in [6] to normal regions.
Remark 3.
Compared with [22], in this article, we dropped off the conditions of “Lipschitz continuous”, “pseudomonotone plus”, and/or “strongly pseudomonotone” in corresponding results.
Remark 4.
Similar to [23,24], our algorithms can be used in Machine Learning and Artificial Intelligence.

Funding

The research received no external funding.

Data Availability Statement

All data are in the article.

Conflicts of Interest

The author declares no conflict of interest.

References

  1. Kelley, J.E. The Cutting Plane Method for Solving Convex Programs. J. SIAM 1960, 8, 703–712. [Google Scholar]
  2. Gon, J.-L.; Vial, J.-P. Cutting Planes and Column Generation Techniques with the Projective Algorithm. J. Optim. Theory Appl. 1990, 65, 409–429. [Google Scholar]
  3. Merle, O.D. Interior Points and Cutting Palnes: A Development and Implementation of Methods for Convex Optimization and Large Scale Structured Linear Programming. Ph.D. Thesis, Department of Management Studies, University of Geneva, Geneva, Switzerland, 1995. (In French). [Google Scholar]
  4. Bahn, O.; Gon, J.-L.; Vial, J.-P.; Merle, O.D. Experimental Behaviour of an Interior Point Cutting Plane Algorithm for Convex Programming: An Application to Geometric Programming. Discret. Appl. Math. 1994, 49, 3–23. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  5. Bahn, O.; Merle, O.D.; Gon, J.-L.; Vial, J.-P. A Cutting Plane Method from Analytic Centers for Stochastic Programming. Math. Program. 1995, 69, 45–73. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  6. Shen, J.; Pang, L.P. A Proximal Analytic Center Cutting Plane Algorithm for Solving Variational Inequality Problems. J. Appl. Math. 2012, 2012, 503242. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  7. Goffin, J.; Luo, Z.; Ye, Y. Complexity Analysis of an Interior-Point Cutting Plane Method for Convex Feasibility Problem. SIAM J. Optim. 1996, 6, 638–652. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  8. Zabotin, I.Y.; Yarullin, R.S. Cutting-Plane Method Based on Epigraph Approximation with Discarding the Cutting Planes. Autom. Remote Control. Syst. Anal. Oper. Res. 2015, 76, 1966–1975. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  9. He, S.; Wu, T. A Modified Subgradient Extragradient Method for Solving Monotone Variational Inequalities. J. Inequalities Appl. 2017, 2017, 89. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  10. Auslender, A. Optimisation; Méthodes Numériques (Livre); Masson: Paris, France, 1976. [Google Scholar]
  11. Farkas, G.A. Fourier-fele Mechanikaiely Alkalmazfisai. Math. Természettudományi Értesitö 1894, 12, 457–472. [Google Scholar]
  12. Minkowski, H. Geometrie der Zahlen; Teubner: Leipzig, Germany, 1896. [Google Scholar]
  13. Weyl, H. Elementire Theorie der Konvexen Polyeder. Comment. Math. Helv. 1935, 7, 290–306. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  14. Nash, J. Non-Cooperative Games. Ann. Math. Second. Ser. 1951, 5, 286–295. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  15. Fischer, A.; Herrich, M.; Schonefeld, K. Generalized Nash Equilibrium Problems, Recent Advances and Challenges. Pesqui. Oper. 2014, 34, 521–558. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  16. Faraci, F.; Raciti, F. On Generalized Nash Equilibrium in Infinite Dimension: The Lagrange Multipliers Approach. Optimization 2015, 64, 321–338. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  17. Boilan, B. Nash Equilibrium for a Special Class of Interval Functions, Application to Economy. Procedia Econ. Financ. 2015, 22, 587–594. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  18. Konnov, I.V.; Volotskaya, E.O. Mixed Variational Inequalities and Economic Equilibrium Problems. J. Appl. Math. 2002, 2, 289–314. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  19. Golshtein, E.G.; Tretyakov, N.V. Modified Lagrange Functions; Nauka: Moscow, Russia, 1989. [Google Scholar]
  20. Murphy, F.H.; Sherali, H.D.; Soyster, A.L. A Mathematical Programming Approach for Determining Oligopolistic Market Equilibrium. Math. Program. 1982, 24, 92–106. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  21. Hartman, P.; Stampacchia, G. On Some Non-Linear Elliptic Differential Functional Equations. Acta Math. 1966, 115, 271–310. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  22. Zeng, R. Analytic Center Cutting Plane Methods for Variational Inequalities over Convex Bodies. J. Inequalities Appl. 2018, 2018, 87. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  23. Makarychev, Y.; Manoj, S.; Ovsiankin, M. Streaming Algorithms for Ellipsoidal Approximation of Convex Polytopes. In Proceedings of the Machine Learning Research 2022, Baltimore, MD, USA, 17–23 July 2022; Volume 178, pp. 1–24. [Google Scholar]
  24. Wang, Y.; van Bremen, T.; Pu, J.; Wang, Y. Fast Algorithms for Relational Marginal Polytopes. In Proceedings of the Thirtieth International Joint Conference on Artificial Intelligence (IJCAI-21), Montreal, QB, Canada, 19–26 August 2021; pp. 4266–4274. [Google Scholar]
Disclaimer/Publisher’s Note: The statements, opinions and data contained in all publications are solely those of the individual author(s) and contributor(s) and not of MDPI and/or the editor(s). MDPI and/or the editor(s) disclaim responsibility for any injury to people or property resulting from any ideas, methods, instructions or products referred to in the content.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Zeng, R. Proximal Analytic Center Cutting Plane Algorithms for Variational Inequalities and Nash Economic Equilibrium. Mathematics 2024, 12, 177. https://doi.org/10.3390/math12020177

AMA Style

Zeng R. Proximal Analytic Center Cutting Plane Algorithms for Variational Inequalities and Nash Economic Equilibrium. Mathematics. 2024; 12(2):177. https://doi.org/10.3390/math12020177

Chicago/Turabian Style

Zeng, Renying. 2024. "Proximal Analytic Center Cutting Plane Algorithms for Variational Inequalities and Nash Economic Equilibrium" Mathematics 12, no. 2: 177. https://doi.org/10.3390/math12020177

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop